Oireachtas Joint and Select Committees

Thursday, 26 February 2015

Committee of Inquiry into the Banking Crisis

Context Phase

Professor Terrence McDonough:

I thank the committee for inviting me to testify before it today. Along with the rest of the nation, I am looking forward to learning about many of the specific events and decisions leading up to the Irish banking crisis. In contrast, however, I will concentrate on addressing today's brief, which concerns the international, European and Irish policy context of the banking crisis. In doing so, I will be presenting a macroeconomic analysis of the overall crisis which still faces the world's peoples today, at least seven years after its inauguration.

It is important to understand that the situation affecting Ireland at the time of the banking guarantee cannot be characterised only as a financial crisis. Instead, Ireland at this time was caught up in a perfect storm, one whose great winds have periodically abated only to blow up again. It is popular in some quarters to refer to Ireland's crisis as homegrown, and it is certainly true that one storm front blew up within the borders of Ireland. However, 2008 saw the tragic convergence of this front with two other influences, one the global storm of the international crisis of global neoliberalism. This blew Ireland against the other influence, namely, the unforgiving shores of the euro system. We do not have to go all the way back to the proverbial butterfly flapping its wings to find the origins of this maelstrom. The global crisis, the European crisis and the Irish crisis all find their origins in the same basic institutions of the age. All are rooted in the four institutions of globalisation, neoliberalism, repression of labour and financialisation.

What are these institutions? Globalisationis the disintegration of production processes into their component parts and the location of each of these components in that area of the world most congenial to making profits. The production process is then reintegrated through free trade across borders. This process brings employers and workers face to face across the globe. Neoliberalismis a complex phenomenon. It can perhaps be most succinctly described as market fundamentalism, a belief that important social decisions about production and income distribution are almost always and everywhere best left to be determined in markets. This idea manifests itself in institutions like the World Trade Organisation, policies like deregulation and privatisation and ideologies like free market economics. The repression of labourinvolves the erosion of the power of labour to defend its organisations, working conditions and standard of living. It is most dramatically evidenced in the decline in union density. Financialisation, according to the American economist Jerry Epstein, "refers to the increasing importance of financial markets, financial motives, financial institutions, and financial elites in the operation of the economy and its governing institutions, both at the national and international level".

All these institutions date from the early 1980s. Their beginnings are marked by the political victories of Ronald Reagan in the United States and Margaret Thatcher in the United Kingdom. These new institutions can be collectively labelled the era of global neoliberalism. This new stage of capitalism at first led to recovery. In the 1970s, capitalism was in a period which has come to be known as the Great Stagflation, a condition of simultaneous high unemployment and high inflation which was unpredicted by the Keynesian economics of the time. Together, globalisation, financialisation, neoliberalism and the loss of labour influence led to a period known in some quarters as the Great Moderation. Profit rates, which had been falling from the late 1960s, bottomed out in the early 1980s and over time returned to their previous levels. Growth recovered, although it did not reach the standards of the earlier post-Second World War period. Employment rose and inflation fell and remained low.

However, this economic recovery is only one side of the story. The same set of institutions which led to the global neoliberal recovery from stagflation would eventually create the most serious economic crisis since the Great Depression. Problems became evident almost immediately. Globalisation led to the unification of previously separate national markets for goods and services. Competition within this new larger market led to the emergence of excess capacity in many industries. Labour's loss of bargaining power led to the stagnation of real median family income in the United States. This wage stagnation occurred despite the continual increase in the productive capacity of labour. These two factors, excess capacity and stagnant wages, led to a rate of investment which, while positive, was relatively sluggish by historical standards. This relatively sluggish investment was accompanied by restored profitability. If the restored profits were not being invested in productive plant and equipment, where could they go? Financialisation made it increasingly easy to fund the purchase of various categories of assets, driving up their prices and creating capital gains, which could only encourage further speculation in asset prices. Borrowing on the basis of rising asset prices temporarily sustained demand in the face of sluggish investment and stagnant wages. When the asset bubble burst, however, the full force of listless investment and low wages was felt in the emergence of what was, in Keynesian terms, a crisis of inadequate demand. For the ordinary household, it was a crisis of unemployment.

That is the global context and, naturally, we are much more concerned with the specific situation of Ireland.

A close look at the origins of the Celtic tiger, however, reveals that it was a creature of these same four institutions of global neoliberalism, namely, globalisation, neoliberalism, the repression of labour and financialisation. As is often the case in Ireland, we had to wait a few years for the advent of global neoliberalism - Irish style. For Ireland, the key date is 1987. A neoliberal approach to government in Ireland began when a minority Fianna Fáil Government came to power in 1987. Minority status led to seeking a consensus economic strategy which could attract the support of other parties. It was supported by Fine Gael’s adoption of the Tallaght strategy under the leadership of Alan Dukes. Two years later the neoliberal Progressive Democrats entered coalition with Fianna Fáil. O’Riain and O’Connell summarise the turnaround in public spending:

Restoring order to the public finances was achieved by severe cutbacks in public expenditure in 1987-1990. Total current spending fell by over ten percentage points in real terms between 1987 and 1989. Total current spending fell from 57% of gross national product in 1985 to 42% in 1990.

The fall in expenditure created room for tax cuts. The top rate of income tax fell from 60% to 48% over five years. Basic corporate income tax rates also fell.

In addition to embarking on a new macroeconomic strategy, the new Fianna Fáil Government also convened the first of a series of tripartite industrial negotiations leading to a national partnership agreement, the Programme for National Recovery, PNR. For the unions’ part, they could sense a rightward shift in the political system and feared the Government might be capable of importing the Thatcherite strategy of a massive attack on the unions aimed at negating their economic, social and political influence. The PNR established a neoliberal pattern of achieving wage moderation through the promise of future tax cuts. Frank Barry calculates these tax cuts accounted for about one third of the increases in take-home pay to 2004. Such moderation under social partnership led to a falling wage share. The wage share was 71 % of gross domestic product in 1986 and fell to 54% in 2001. Days lost through industrial disputes dropped off drastically beginning in 1987. Accordingly, the repression of labour in Ireland led not to wage stagnation, as in the United States, but to wage moderation under social partnership.

The social partnership process was careful not to jeopardise Ireland’s traditional internationalisation strategy. Teague and Donaghey conclude that social partnership operated “hand-in-glove with the wider policy of economic openness”. The Single European Act came into effect in 1987 and was approved by referendum in the same year. The implementation of the Single Market coincides with a boom in foreign employment in Ireland, with such jobs growing by 50% between 1987 and 2000. The Single European Act was accompanied by plans to expand Structural Funds spending. Structural Funds were doubled in 1988 and again in 1993. A new Industrial Development Agency, IDA, strategic plan was unveiled in 1983. The new strategy would concentrate on technologically advanced firms with high potential for market growth. These developments copperfastened globalisation as an essential element of Ireland’s growth strategy.

The year 1987 also saw the investment hunting capacity of the IDA applied in a new realm. It was decided by the incoming Government to target investment in international financial services through the establishment of the International Financial Services Centre, IFSC. By 1999, attracted by light touch regulation, 66% of all FDI, foreign direct investment, inflows were accounted for by the IFSC. It was the source of 24% of all services exports. The IFSC would be an important conduit for foreign capital flows and was central to Ireland’s participation in transnational financialisation.

Irish participation in the global neoliberal social order was no longer in doubt and this institutional framework underpinned the advent of the famous Celtic tiger. Of course, the tiger is also now infamous because, as was the case at the global level, the elements of global neoliberalism would not only set the conditions for Ireland’s rise but also its spectacular fall from grace. Under Ireland’s peculiar labour institutions, wages rose but the level of inequality rose much faster. The fear of Thatcherism had fed into the formation of social partnership. As noted before, wage moderation was traded for tax cuts. This tendency was strongly reinforced by the perceived need to compete globally through low taxes and a neoliberal policy preference for minimising the capacity of the State.

The economic momentum of the Celtic tiger eventually fed into blowing up the real estate market. Financialisation provided the wind beneath the wings of the Irish asset bubble. Rising levels of inequality created an aspiration for levels of consumption which for many could not be supported from current income. Rising house prices provided an expensive asset of expanding value for those in the housing market and collateral for borrowing by those who already owned their own homes. Household debt rose from less than 120% of disposable income in 2003 to 220% in 2009. The bubble in the property market provided an alternative source of government income through stamp duty and construction-related VAT, compensating to some extent for the overall low tax regime.

Ireland was now poised for crisis. We had a property bubble which could be traced back to financialisation. We had high levels of household debt which could be traced to the property bubble and rising inequality. We had a low tax regime which could be traced back to the repression of labour, globalisation and neoliberalism. The property bubble burst in 2007, endangering the banking system. The global crisis hit in 2008, intensifying Irish problems. The collapse of banking, construction and the tax regime produced a fiscal crisis. The financial crisis, the fiscal crisis and unsustainable household debt then created an unemployment crisis. It was at this point that the global storm front and the Irish turbulence combined ran up against the sea cliffs of the inflexible euro system. This euro system was also rooted in global neoliberalism, a global neoliberalism - euro style. The drive for globalisation led to the Single European Market. Globalisation linked with financialisation to create the euro currency. The Single European Market and the euro led to trade surpluses in some countries that were recycled into blowing up asset bubbles and trade deficits in other countries which weakened their fiscal positions. Financialisation, linked with a strong dose of neoliberal ideology, led to a fiercely independent European Central Bank aggressively limiting its responsibility to inflation control. Neoliberal ideas of small government and limited intervention in private markets, with the declining influence of labour, led to a monetary union without any fiscal capacity to address problems through increased government spending at European level. Together the Single European Market, the euro, the European Central Bank and limited fiscal capacity can be said to constitute the euro system.

When the turbulence hit, the euro system made sure Ireland could find no haven through devaluing its currency, conducting an independent monetary policy or receive help through fiscal stimulus. The euro rules have forced Ireland to cut spending and raise taxes in the teeth of a depression. Instead of a port in the storm, the backwash from the euro cliff intensified the maelstrom. On 29 September 2008, in the dead of night, Ireland desperately tried to signal for help, but the cannon broke loose and holed the ship of State below the waterline.

How could this catastrophe have been avoided? The only path was to have seen the storm coming and been prepared for it. This is not a question, as some have recommended, of hiring more economists in the Department of Finance. In fact, professional politicians and professional economists in the lead up to these events all saw the world in much the same way.

To avoid the storm, both would have had to see the world differently. I have lived for 20 years in Galway. It is said of the weather in Galway that it is either raining or about to rain. Similarly, in the mainstream economic view, the economy is either calm or rapidly becoming calmer. This theory may barely pass muster in good times, but to prepare for a storm you have to see the economy as potentially tempestuous and riven with conflict and contradictions. A view of the capitalist economy which ignores its historical dynamics, which sees it as a haven of harmonious give and take, a peaceful equilibrium of supply and demand, which works best when interfered with least, will inevitably lead to foundering on hidden shoals amidst unexpected turbulence. This is where Ireland still finds itself today.

Comments

No comments

Log in or join to post a public comment.